The Nonexistence of Representative Agents

Working Paper: CEPR ID: DP13397

Authors: Matthew O. Jackson; Leeat Yariv

Abstract: We characterize environments in which there exists a representative agent: an agent who inherits the structure of preferences of the population that she represents. The existence of such a representative agent imposes strong restrictions on individual utility functions, requiring them to be linear in the allocation and additively separable in any parameter that characterizes agents' preferences (e.g., a risk aversion parameter, a discount factor, etc.). Commonly used classes of utility functions (exponentially discounted utility functions, CRRA or CARA utility functions, logarithmic functions, etc.) do not admit a representative agent.

Keywords: representative agents; preference aggregation; revealed preference; collective decisions

JEL Codes: D72; D71; D03; D11; E24


Causal Claims Network Graph

Edges that are evidenced by causal inference methods are in orange, and the rest are in light blue.


Causal Claims

CauseEffect
Existence of a representative agent (D84)Strong restrictions on individual utility functions (D11)
Strong restrictions on individual utility functions (D11)Utility functions must be linear in allocation and additively separable in parameters (D11)
Commonly used utility functions (CRRA, CARA, logarithmic) (D11)Do not allow for a representative agent (D79)
CRRA utility functions (D11)Representative agent's utility cannot maintain constant relative risk aversion unless all agents have identical risk aversion parameters (D11)
Only parameterized classes of utility functions that are separable in agents' utility parameters (D11)Can admit a representative agent when consumption is common (D10)
When consumption is private (D10)Requirements become more demanding for admitting a representative agent (D79)
Commonly used utility functions in economic modeling (C51)Do not satisfy the necessary restrictions for the existence of a representative agent (D52)

Back to index